Following the recent
decisions by several central banks to set negative benchmark interest rates – in
addition to Japan, most notably the European Central Bank (ECB) and subsequently
Switzerland, Denmark and Sweden – there are some repercussions that need to be
considered by Trade Financiers.
There are several
basic aims in moving benchmark interest rates into negative territory, predominantly
linked to either:
- weakening a currency, thereby making its exports more attractive,
and increasing the cost of imports in order to stave off deflation; or
- boosting spending by discouraging savings and promoting
borrowing.
The latter is
essentially aimed at banks: by making central bank deposits costly, the theory is
that they will need to deploy their deposits elsewhere, hopefully in the form
of loans which can stimulate an economy.
In turn, the interbank reference rates (such as LIBOR and EURIBOR) reflect
the impact of the central bank rates and have consequently also gone negative
in a number of cases.
This causes some
issues for lines of business that use interest rate benchmarks as a mutually
agreeable proxy for the cost of funds for a given period in a specified
currency.
Trade Finance is
one such line of business, especially since the financing is predominantly
risk-based and pricing is typically quoted on a “reference rate plus risk
margin” basis, even though the underlying transactions are not deposits.
What are we currently seeing in the
market?
Our understanding
is that it is becoming commonplace for institutions to set a floor of “zero” for
the reference rate in master or transactional agreements, by using wording such
as: ''If LIBOR is less
than zero at any time of determination, then LIBOR shall be deemed to be zero''.
Why is this a growing trend?
Banks must assess
and mitigate risk, in this case interest rate risk.
So what is the issue with setting a zero
floor?
Clients may
question why the perceived benefit of a negative (i.e. cheaper) rate is not
being passed on to them. In reality though, it is not “free money” being
provided by the central banks which is then not being passed on to customers; it
is a disincentive to holding excess liquidity.
Consider the following related scenarios
LIABILITIES: Clients
place funds on deposit with a bank. If the banks receive more deposits than
they can redeploy profitably elsewhere (or have to retain some of these funds
for regulatory reasons), they typically need to place the excess with a relevant
central bank at the prevailing rate. If this rate is negative, the bank is
effectively incurring a cost when placing these funds. In turn, these costs are
sometimes then reflected in the negative deposit rates charged to clients (although
it may not be always the case).
ASSETS: Conversely,
if a bank is creating an asset by lending money to a client, it will need to
use funds it has obtained from the liabilities side of its balance sheet. As
explained above, the cost of obtaining these funds may be impacted by the negative
benchmark rates.
What should you do?
In this context,
each institution needs to assess how and where it obtains its funding in order
to finance assets, and what an appropriate rate may be.
One way of
addressing the issue is by using a “cost of funds” rate rather than a benchmark
rate, however in practice this also has its challenges as it is harder for a
third party (e.g. a borrower) to determine whether the lender’s cost of funds
are correct or appropriate.
Any queries emanating from this paper can be addressed to Paul Coles, ITFA Board Member - Market Practice.
Disclaimer: This
information does not constitute legal advice and is for educational purposes
only. You should not rely on this opinion as an alternative to seeking
legal advice.
No comments:
Post a Comment